Search This Blog


This is a photo of the National Register of Historic Places listing with reference number 7000063

Sunday, December 4, 2011

FORMER DELPHI EXEC.S PAY FINES AND DISGORGEMENT FOR SECURITIES LAWS VIOLATIONS

The following excerpt is from the SEC website: “ Securities and Exchange Commission today announced that the Honorable Avern Cohn, U.S. District Judge for the Eastern District of Michigan, entered final judgments as to Paul Free, the former Chief Accounting Officer and Controller of Delphi Corporation, and J.T. Battenberg, III, the former Chief Executive Officer of Delphi, and ordered them to pay disgorgement and penalties for federal securities law violations found by a jury. The Court also entered a permanent injunction for fraud and other securities law violations against Free. Delphi is an auto parts manufacturer with headquarters in Troy, Michigan. On January 13, 2011, a jury returned a verdict in favor of the SEC and against Free and Battenberg for violating the federal securities laws. Specifically, the jury found that Battenberg violated the books and records and misrepresentations to accountants provisions of the federal securities laws for his role in the improper accounting for Delphi’s portrayal of $202 million of Delphi’s $237 million warranty settlement with General Motors Corporation (“GM”) in September 2000 as related to pension and other post-employment benefits. As a result, Delphi filed materially false and misleading financial statements in the company’s third quarter 2000 quarterly report on Form 10-Q and its fiscal year 2000 annual report on Form 10-K. In addition, the jury found Free liable on fraud and other charges brought by the Commission for his role in Delphi’s false and misleading accounting for two financing transactions at year-end 2000 -- one involving nearly Delphi’s entire inventory of precious metals necessary to the manufacture of catalytic converters, and one involving Delphi’s inventory of generator cores and batteries – which Delphi falsely claimed as inventory sales; as well as Delphi’s false and misleading accounting for a $20 million payment that it received from Electronic Data Systems (“EDS”) in December 2001 as a rebate (income) rather than as a loan. The jury further found that Free violated the books and records and misrepresentations to accountants provisions of the federal securities laws for his role in the GM warranty transaction. On March 8, 2011, the Court entered partial judgment on liability in accord with the jury’s findings. Thereafter, on October 31, 2011, at the conclusion of the remedies phase of the case, and based upon the jury verdicts, the Court entered final judgments as to Free and Battenberg. The Court enjoined Free from future violations of Sections 10(b) and 13(b)(5) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (“Exchange Act”), Rules 10b-5, 13b2-1 and 13b2-2 promulgated thereunder, and Section 20(e) of the Exchange Act for aiding and abetting Delphi’s violations of Sections 13(a), 13(b)(2)(A) and 13(b)(2)(B) of the Exchange Act and Rules 12b-20, 13a-1 and 13a-13 promulgated thereunder. The Court further ordered Free to disgorge $38,000 in profits and to pay a penalty of $80,500. In addition, the Court found Battenberg liable for violations of Section 13(b)(5) of the Exchange Act, and Rules 13b2-1 and 13b2-2 promulgated thereunder. The Court ordered Battenberg to disgorge $198,500 in profits and to pay a penalty of $16,500. During the trial, the Commission settled with two individual defendants – Catherine Rozanski, Delphi’s former Director of Financial Accounting and Reporting, and Milan Belans, Delphi’s former Director of Capital Planning, Structured Finance and Pension Analysis. Rozanski consented to the entry of an injunction from future violations of Section 17(a) of the Securities Act of 1933 (Securities Act) and Sections 10(b) and 13(b)(5) of the Exchange Act and Rules 10b-5 and 13b2-1 thereunder, and aiding and abetting violations of Sections 13(a), 13(b)(2)(A) and 13(b)(2)(B) of the Exchange Act and Rules 12b-20 and13a-1 thereunder. Rozanski also consented to pay a $40,000 civil money penalty. In settling the Commission’s claims, Rozanski neither admitted nor denied the Commission’s allegations. In addition, separately, without admitting or denying the Commission’s findings, Rozanski consented to the institution of administrative proceedings pursuant to Rule 102(e)(3) of the Commission’s Rules of Practice, suspending her from appearing or practicing before the Commission as an accountant, with a right to apply for reinstatement after three years, based on the entry of the injunction. The Commission’s Complaint against Rozanski alleged that as a result of her participation in the EDS $20 million payment transaction, described above, Delphi filed materially false and misleading financial statements in the company’s 2001 Form 10-K. Moreover, during the trial, Belans consented to the entry of an injunction from future violations of Section 17(a) of the Securities Act and Sections 10(b) and 13(b)(5) of the Exchange Act and Rules 10b-5 and 13b2-1 thereunder, and aiding and abetting violations of Sections 13(a) and 13(b)(2)(A) of the Exchange Act and Rules 12b-20, 13a-1 and 13a-13 thereunder. Belans also consented to pay disgorgement of $17,835, together with prejudgment interest thereon in the amount of $13,865, and a $55,800 civil money penalty. In settling the Commission’s claims, Belans neither admitted nor denied the Commission’s allegations. In addition, separately, without admitting or denying the Commission’s findings, Belans consented to the institution of settled administrative proceedings pursuant to Rule 102(e)(3) of the Commission’s Rules of Practice, suspending him from appearing or practicing before the Commission as an accountant, with a right to apply for reinstatement after five years, based on the entry of the injunction. The Commission’s Complaint against Belans alleged that Belans engaged in the GM warranty settlement transaction and the inventory transactions described above, which resulted in Delphi filing materially false and misleading financial statements in the company’s quarterly report on Form 10-Q for third quarter 2000, and on the company’s annual report on Form 10-K for the fiscal year ended December 31, 2000. The Commission originally filed suit against Delphi and 13 individual defendants on October 30, 2006. Delphi and six individual defendants settled with the Commission at that time. The Commission entered into settlements with two individual defendants and voluntarily dismissed another prior to trial. Finally, based upon the Court’s permanent injunction of Free, the Commission entered an order instituting public administrative proceedings and imposing remedial sanctions pursuant to Rule 102(e) of the Commission’s Rules of Practice. The Commission temporarily suspended Free from appearing or practicing before the Commission. The suspension may become permanent if Free does not file a petition with the Commission within thirty days. This concludes the Commission’s federal district court litigation.”

Saturday, December 3, 2011

SEC WANTS "ROBUST" INSPECTIONS AT BROKER-DEALER BRANCH OFFICES

The following excerpt was received as an e-mail from the SEC: "Washington, DC, November 30, 2011 – The Securities and Exchange Commission’s Office of Compliance Inspections and Examinations (OCIE) and the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA) today issued a Risk Alert and a Regulatory Notice on broker-dealer branch inspections, and offered suggestions to help securities industry firms better perform this key supervisory function. “A robust process for self-inspection of branch offices is a critical element of a firm’s compliance and supervision process, and a vital part of a comprehensive risk management program,” said Carlo di Florio, Director of OCIE. “This Risk Alert highlights practices that are characteristic of effective branch office supervisory systems, and describes major deficiencies that SEC and FINRA examiners have found in the branch inspection process.” “An effective risk based branch office inspection program is an important component of a broker-dealer’s supervisory system and, when constructed and implemented reasonably, it can better protect investors and the firm’s own interests,” said Stephen Luparello, Vice Chairman of FINRA. “FINRA encourages broker-dealers to review this guidance and consider enhancements to their own branch office inspection programs.” Along with specific requirements outlined in the report, effective practices observed by examiners include: Using risk analysis to identify whether individual non-supervising branches should be inspected more frequently than the FINRA-required minimum three-year cycle, with more frequent inspections of branches meeting certain risk criteria. In addition, some firms conduct “re-audits” when routine inspections reveal a high number of deficiencies, repeat deficiencies, or serious deficiencies. Typically, these re-audits and audits for cause are conducted as unannounced inspections. Using surveillance reports and employing current technology and techniques to help identify risks and develop a customized approach for branch office inspections based on the type of business conducted at each branch. Employing comprehensive checklists that incorporate previous inspection findings and trends noted in internal reports such as audit reports. Conducting unannounced branch inspections either randomly or based on certain risk factors. “Surprise” exams may yield a more realistic picture of a broker-dealer’s supervisory system as they reduce the risk that individual RRs and principals might attempt to falsify, conceal, or destroy records in anticipation for an internal inspection. Involving qualified senior personnel in several branch office examinations each year. Incorporating findings of branch office inspections into management information or risk management systems and using a centralized, comprehensive compliance database that enables compliance personnel in various offices to access to information about all of the firm’s RRs and their business activities. Such a system appears to be very useful when supervising independent contractor RRs dispersed across a broad geographic area. Providing branch office managers with the firm’s internal inspection findings and requiring them to take and document corrective action. Tracking corrective action taken by each branch office manager in response to branch audit findings. Elevating the frequency of branch inspections, or their scope, or both, in cases where registered personnel are allowed to conduct business activities other than as associated persons of a broker-dealer, for example away from the firm. This is the second in a continuing series of Risk Alerts that the SEC’s national examination staff expects to issue. These documents are intended to alert senior management, risk management, and compliance managers in the securities industry to significant risks identified by the SEC’s national examination staff, so that industry members can more effectively address those risks. The following SEC staff contributed substantially to preparing this Risk Alert: Julius Leiman-Carbia, Daniel Gregus, Rich Hannibal, George Kramer, Barbara Lorenzen and Karol Pollock The following FINRA staff also contributed substantially to preparing this Risk Alert: Michael Rufino, Paul Fagone, Donald Litteau and George Walz."

SEC COMMISSIONER SOMMER SPEECH ON CORPORATE, SECURITIES AND FINANCIAL LAW

The following excerpt is from the SEC website: Speech by SEC Commissioner: Twelfth Annual A.A. Sommer, Jr. Lecture on Corporate, Securities and Financial Law by Commissioner Troy A. Paredes U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission New York, NY October 27, 2011 Thank you for the generous introduction. And thank you to Fordham Law School for kindly inviting me to deliver the Twelfth Annual A.A. Sommer, Jr. Lecture on Corporate, Securities and Financial Law. Before beginning my remarks, let me dispense with one formality and remind you that the views I express here today are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Securities and Exchange Commission or my fellow Commissioners. Given all that has occurred since I joined the Commission in 2008 — from the financial crisis, to Dodd-Frank, to numerous rules and regulations that the SEC has advanced, to important Supreme Court decisions — I could speak to any number of current developments. Instead of choosing a topic that is uniquely “of the moment,” however, I have decided to speak about something that has been a constant — from 1933 when the Securities Act was adopted through today — when considering and evaluating the federal securities laws: disclosure. As the professors here know, being a professor is a terrific job. You enjoy the fulfillment of teaching students and the enthusiasm that goes with researching and writing about whatever you want to tackle. During my time as a professor of corporate and securities law, a big part of my scholarly agenda focused on thinking about mandatory disclosure as a regulatory mechanism. What is the economic rationale for mandatory disclosure? Why not let voluntary disclosure do the trick? What exact information do investors need? How should what is disclosed be disclosed? How do real people make real decisions with the information they have? Is the assumption of rational behavior viable? As I took a deep dive into the relevant legal, economic, and psychological literatures, I came to a quick realization. Namely, I could not properly study the role of disclosure under the federal securities laws without reading the work and engaging the insights of Al Sommer. In preparing for this lecture, I revisited some of Al Sommer’s speeches and other writings, including the landmark report that the SEC Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure, which he chaired, finished in 1977. With the more complete perspective that I now have — having now served for over three years as a Commissioner myself — I was taken by how smart, nuanced, and prescient Al Sommer’s ideas and observations were. I never had the pleasure of meeting Al Sommer, but I have no doubt that I could have talked to him for hours and learned a lot. And I very much enjoyed meeting Starr and the other members of the Sommer family who have joined us this evening. Given my longstanding interest in the philosophy and practice of disclosure — about which Al Sommer shared so many important thoughts — I feel especially fortunate to have the chance to deliver this lecture in his honor. * * * * There is hereby established a Securities and Exchange Commission . . . to be composed of five commissioners to be appointed by the President by and with the advice and consent of the Senate. So provides section 4(a) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. Until the SEC was created in 1934, the Federal Trade Commission had administered the federal securities laws, then consisting of the Securities Act of 1933. Much has changed since then. Scores of influential developments have shaped the course of federal securities regulation over the SEC’s nearly 80-year history.1 Here is a sampling: After the ’33 and ’34 Acts came the Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935, the Trust Indenture Act of 1939, and the Investment Company and Investment Advisers Acts of 1940. Other notable legislative developments have included the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act, the National Securities Markets Improvement Act, the Securities Litigation Uniform Standards Act, and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. In 2010, following the financial crisis of 2008, Congress passed, and the President signed into law, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, which overhauls the regulatory regime that governs our financial markets, including significant changes to the federal securities laws. Together, Congress and the President enact the relevant statutes, but the SEC administers them as an independent agency. It goes without saying that since its founding, the SEC has been an active regulator. Over the past few years alone, the SEC has advanced a number of initiatives — some related to Dodd-Frank and others not — concerning matters such as credit rating agencies; the election of board members; public company compensation and governance disclosures; shareholder “say on pay”; money market funds; the structure of our equity markets; short selling; broker-dealer risk management controls; municipal offerings; asset securitization; clearing agencies; over-the-counter derivatives; investment adviser disclosures; investment adviser “pay to play” arrangements; the custody of advisory client assets; whistleblowers; and the “Volcker Rule.” The courts also have been instrumental in determining the reach and substance of securities regulation through their interpretations of the underlying statutes and rules and regulations. Consider, for example, the practical impact of U.S. Supreme Court cases such as Howey, Ralston Purina, Basic, Ernst & Ernst, TSC Industries, Blue Chip Stamps, Central Bank, Chiarella, O’Hagan, Dura, and Stoneridge. The Roberts Court has been particularly influential in shaping the regulatory landscape recently, having handed down in the past couple of years Jones (concerning investment advisory fees), Merck (concerning the statute of limitations in private lawsuits for fraud under Section 10(b) of the ’34 Act), Morrison (concerning the extraterritorial reach of Section 10(b)), Matrixx (concerning materiality), Halliburton (concerning class certification), and Janus (concerning the reach of primary liability under Rule 10b-5). * * * * Even as the superstructure of securities regulation has evolved over the decades with the accretion of statutory changes and new rules, regulations, and judicial opinions, the foundational cornerstone of the regulatory regime has remained fixed: It is disclosure. For over 75 years, the SEC’s signature mandate has been to use disclosure to promote transparency. Louis Brandeis, whose ideas were a major influence on the disclosure philosophy of regulation that continues to animate the federal securities laws, summed things up as early as 1914: “Publicity is justly commended as a remedy for social and industrial diseases. Sunlight is said to be the best of disinfectants; electric light the most efficient policeman.”2 Nearly 20 years later, in his March 29, 1933, message to Congress, President Roosevelt built on Brandeis’s sentiment, stating: Of course, the Federal Government cannot and should not take any action which might be construed as approving or guaranteeing that newly issued securities are sound in the sense that their value will be maintained or that the properties which they represent will earn profit. There is, however, an obligation upon us to insist that every issue of new securities to be sold in interstate commerce shall be accompanied by full publicity and information, and that no essentially important element attending the issue shall be concealed from the buying public.3 Louis Loss, another key figure in the intellectual history of securities regulation, had this to say about disclosure: “People who are forced to undress in public will presumably pay some attention to their figures.”4 But the one who captured how disclosure can influence behavior most colorfully is Al Sommer: “Very simply put,” he said, “if every instance of adultery had to be disclosed, there would probably be less adultery.” 5 The essence of the disclosure philosophy of securities regulation is that, when armed with information, investors are well-positioned to evaluate their investment opportunities and to allocate their capital as they see fit. When investors are able to make informed decisions, it is more likely that the financial capital that circulates in our economy will be put to more productive uses than if investors did not have the benefit of useful information. Explaining the report of the Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure, Al Sommer made the point this way: [T]he Committee recognized that in any society needs and demands will exceed available resources. When that is the case, as it universally is, it is necessary that the scarce resources be allocated. It is axiomatic that such allocation will be best achieved if those involved in allocation decisions have the benefit of reliable, timely and sufficient information. Thus, in making investment decisions, investors are likeliest to make efficient allocations of resources if they have available information with those characteristics.6 By ensuring that investors have the information they need to make informed decisions, mandatory disclosure, in turn, leverages market discipline as a means of accountability that obviates the need for more substantive government regulation of securities-related activities. Through their investment decisions, investors are able to bring pressure to bear on directors, officers, investment advisers, broker-dealers, and other market participants to serve investor interests. Market participants are incentivized to satisfy investor demands because investors “reward” and “punish” by how and with whom they choose to invest and transact. Furthermore, although a disclosure-based approach to regulation may require certain disclosures, it does not prohibit issuers from raising capital just because the government is skeptical of the offering’s merits, dictate corporate governance arrangements, demand that enterprises be run in a certain way, or otherwise mandate or ban particular conduct.7 In other words, as a regulatory mechanism, disclosure privileges investor choice, favors private ordering over one-size-fits-all mandates, and encourages innovation and competition. The disclosure philosophy of securities regulation does not presuppose that investors are perfect decision makers. Indeed, the more recent teachings of behavioral finance suggest the extent to which investors may err. Even when investors are empowered with extensive disclosures, for example, certain cognitive biases and decision-making shortcuts — so-called “heuristics” — may lead to unfortunate decisions. That said, disclosure regulation puts into practice the view that, overall, the collective judgment of the marketplace — disciplined as it is by market forces — should be respected as a worthy alternative to more substantive government control of private-sector conduct and capital flows. For the test is not whether investors are perfect decision makers; rather, the test is whether it is preferable to leave certain decisions to market institutions instead of relying more on government officials, who also err, to dictate results through regulation. To be clear, even a disclosure-based approach to regulation contemplates a meaningful role for government. The federal securities laws, for example, mandate certain disclosures from companies, mutual funds, investment advisers, broker-dealers, and even investors. Plus, to be useful, disclosures need to be truthful, whether the disclosures are mandated by government or provided voluntarily in response to the demand of investors for more information. Here, the antifraud provisions of the federal securities laws, such as section 10(b) of the ’34 Act and Rule 10b-5 thereunder, are particularly constructive in promoting an effective disclosure regime. * * * * Since the agency’s creation, disclosure has been fundamental to what the Commission does. Accordingly, it seems sensible to call for more disclosure in response to any number of regulatory concerns. But mandatory disclosure is not costless, notwithstanding the considerable benefits that flow from transparency. Once the cost of disclosure is properly accounted for, whether to require even more disclosure becomes a more challenging regulatory decision. The SEC recognized this in asking the Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure some 35 years ago to “assess the costs of the present system of corporate disclosure and to weigh those costs against the benefits its produces.”8 If one carefully balances the costs and benefits of mandatory disclosure when it is put into practice, it becomes apparent that regulatory requirements that demand more disclosure in the name of transparency may not always provide the benefits needed to justify the costs. Leaving it to the marketplace to sort out what, if any, additional information should be forthcoming and under what conditions is sometimes preferable. Two ready examples — one concerning small business and the other concerning “information overload” — help make the point, although I could have selected many other examples from many different contexts. Out-of-pocket compliance costs, which can be considerable, are the most obvious cost of complying with mandatory disclosure requirements. In addition, time and effort committed to meeting regulatory demands can distract valuable resources from more productive efforts that, on net, better serve investors and our economy generally. Financial and other regulatory burdens can be particularly challenging for small businesses. By disproportionately straining new and emerging companies, regulatory burdens can create barriers to entry and expansion. This is problematic because startups and maturing enterprises fuel economic growth, generate new innovations and technologies that improve our standard of living, and are an important source of competitive pressure that disciplines larger enterprises to run themselves more productively. Companies that today are household names can trace their origins to entrepreneurs and innovators of earlier periods who had the wherewithal and backing to start and grow a business. More to the point, if the regulatory regime stifles small business capital formation by making it more difficult and more costly for businesses to raise funds, investors enjoy fewer investment opportunities for putting their money to work. The practical challenge for securities regulators is to strike a balance that avoids unduly stifling the formation and fostering of new and smaller businesses. Fortunately, the federal securities laws have long recognized the need to be measured, as there is a tradition of scaling federal securities regulation in important respects to provide small businesses relief from select burdens that may be especially onerous for them. Consider Section 5 of the Securities Act of 1933. The registration requirements of Section 5 are the centerpiece of that legislation. Nonetheless, the full measure of Section 5’s disclosure obligations does not apply to smaller businesses in practice. Section 3(b) of the ’33 Act, for example, authorizes the SEC to adopt rules exempting certain small offerings from Section 5’s registration requirements, which can be demanding and time consuming. Under Section 3(b), the Commission, several years back, adopted Rules 504 and 505 of Regulation D. In easing disclosure burdens by allowing an issuer to forego a statutory prospectus and registration statement, our rules facilitate capital formation for startups and other small firms long before they consider going public. Rule 506 also has encouraged small business capital formation by providing certainty and predictability in the form of a safe harbor under Section 4(2) of the ’33 Act, which exempts private placements from Section 5. More recently, in 2007, the SEC adopted a host of reforms designed to ease the disclosure burden smaller companies face once they are public.9 The Commission also expanded the number of companies that can avail themselves of the more streamlined and efficient regulatory regime. In my view, there is room to do still more. We need to consider new opportunities to alleviate regulatory demands that stifle the funding and growth of small business. This means that we should press forward on refining the regulatory regime to allow issuers more flexibility to raise capital privately and that we need to consider regulatory changes that address the risk that the regulatory regime itself unduly dissuades companies from going public and listing on U.S. exchanges. Accordingly, I am pleased by the recent discussions that have centered on such worthwhile ideas as: modernizing the prohibition on general solicitations under Regulation D so that businesses can raise funds more efficiently and at lower cost; increasing the 500 shareholder threshold at which a private company is forced to report publicly; substantially increasing the current cap on offerings permitted under Regulation A; and facilitating “crowdfunding” as a means for small business to raise capital more easily from individuals. A number of bills have been introduced in Congress to help promote capital formation in these ways — a common theme of which is that the mandatory disclosure regime should be further scaled and refined. And I am pleased that the President has expressed his intent to “cut away the red tape that prevents too many rapidly growing startup companies from raising capital and going public.”10 We are all better off if businesses can raise the capital they need to undertake cutting-edge research and development, to commercialize new technologies, to expand their capacity, and to create jobs. My second example concerns information overload. Simply put, it is possible for there to be too much information for investors and others to work through constructively. The risk of information overload, in other words, is a cost of mandatory disclosure. Investors are inundated with volumes of information. As then-Commissioner Sommer put it in a 1974 speech, “the expansion of disclosure has gone forward unremittingly.”11 Al Sommer also expressed a measure of discomfort over the “quantity and complexity” of the information that investors face and have to try to digest.12 Suffice it to say, much more is disclosed today than ever before, be it because of government mandates or investor demand or because companies, in taking a defensive posture, decide to disclose more marginally-useful information to reduce the risk that they could be challenged in litigation for not having disclosed enough. By way of quick illustration, take Dodd-Frank. The statute requires public company disclosures regarding board compensation committee consultants;13 executive pay at the company compared to the firm’s financial performance;14 the ratio of the median annual total compensation of the issuer’s employees (excluding the CEO) to the CEO’s annual total compensation;15 employee and director hedging of the value of the issuer’s stock;16 and whether the company has separated the positions of chairman of the board and CEO.17 The bottom-line risk with information overload is that investors will have so much information available to them that they will sometimes be unable to distinguish what is important from what is not. Too frequently, investors do not bother carefully studying the information that is available and get overwhelmed or distracted, misplacing their focus on less important matters. In short, the sheer amount of information can frustrate its effective use. The trouble is that when information is not processed and interpreted effectively, decision making may not improve with additional disclosure. Ironically, if investors are overloaded, more disclosure actually can result in less transparency and worse decisions. Information overload is not a new concern. Consider what constitutes a “material” misstatement or omission under the antifraud provisions of the federal securities laws. Thirty-five years ago, in TSC Industries v. Northway,18 the Supreme Court held that a fact is “material” if “there is a substantial likelihood that a reasonable shareholder would consider it important in deciding how to vote.”19 In rejecting the view that a fact is “material” if an investor “might” find it important, Justice Marshall, writing for the Court, warned against information overload: “[M]anagement’s fear of exposing itself to substantial liability,” Justice Marshall wrote, “may cause it simply to bury the shareholders in an avalanche of trivial information — a result that is hardly conducive to informed decisionmaking.”20 This leads me to a practical suggestion. Disclosure serves key regulatory objectives, but too much disclosure can be counterproductive. The Commission should account for this in fashioning its disclosure regime. We need to consider the impact on investors as disclosure obligations mount and investors are thus presented with more and more information to work through. It may be better for investors to have shorter, more manageable prospectuses and proxy statements, for example, that contain more targeted information instead of lengthy documents that are not fully digested and that in too many instances are entirely ignored. While new disclosures may be required from time to time, we should be open to the prospect that certain disclosures should be more narrowly focused or otherwise scaled back. What is disclosed to investors should be presented, when practicable, in a more accessible way — such as charts, graphs, tables, and summaries — so that the information is more digestible and understandable. Technological advances like the Internet and smartphones allow us to consider new and innovative opportunities for how disclosures can be packaged and distributed to investors. In sum, mandatory disclosure is viewed differently if one recognizes that more information is not always better than less. * * * * If time allowed this evening, we could consider how the role of disclosure informs other current policy discussions, such as the question of imposing a fiduciary obligation on broker-dealers; the impact of pre- and post-trade transparency on the over-the-counter derivatives market; the consequences of bringing more “light” to dark pools; what should be covered by Dodd-Frank’s ban on conflicts of interest in certain securitizations; and whether to further incorporate IFRS into the U.S. financial reporting system. But time doesn’t allow, so let me leave you with this. There is no disagreement that transparency, achieved through disclosure, is central to the federal securities laws. That said, when evaluating the practical effects of particular disclosures, it is not enough to emphasize the benefits of the disclosure; one also has to engage the costs. Citing the goal of “transparency” or noting the disclosure philosophy of securities regulation should not distract from a rigorous analysis of the competing costs and benefits. Indeed, all things considered, some mandatory disclosures may not be warranted. Thank you.”

Friday, December 2, 2011

SEC AND FORMER FDA CHEMIST SETTLE CHARGES

The following excerpt is from the SEC website: The following excerpt is from the SEC website: November 30, 2011 “The Securities and Exchange Commission announced that on November 29, 2011, the Honorable Deborah Chasanow, United States District Judge for the District of Maryland, entered a final judgment against Cheng Yi Liang, in SEC v. Cheng Yi Liang, et al., C.A. No. 8:11-cv-00819-DKC (D. Md.), an insider trading case the SEC filed on March 29, 2011. Liang is a former U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) chemist who worked in the FDA's Center for Drug Evaluation and Research. The complaint, amended June 2, 2011, alleged that from at least July 2006 until March 2011, Liang traded based on confidential information he obtained from the FDA in advance of at least 28 public announcements about FDA drug approval decisions for profits and losses avoided of more than $3.7 million. Liang concealed his trading by trading in eight brokerage accounts in the name of six nominees, including his 84-year-old mother and 87-year-old father, both citizens and residents of China. For example, the SEC alleged that Liang traded in advance of an FDA announcement approving Clinical Data's application for the drug Viibryd. Liang accessed a confidential FDA database that contained critical documents and information about the FDA's review of Clinical Data's application, and then used that information to purchase more than 46,000 shares of Clinical Data at a cost of more than $700,000. After the markets closed on Friday, January 21, 2011, the FDA issued a press release approving Viibryd. Clinical Data's stock price rose by more than 67 percent the following Monday and Liang sold his entire Clinical Data position in less than 15 minutes for a profit of approximately $380,000. To settle the SEC's charges, Liang, without admitting or denying the allegations in the complaint, agreed to entry of a final judgment that: (i) enjoins him from future violations of Section 17(a) of the Securities Act of 1933 and Section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 and Rule 10b-5, thereunder; and (ii) requires Liang to pay disgorgement of $3,776,152, which will be deemed satisfied by the forfeiture order entered in the parallel criminal case, United States v. Cheng Yi Liang, Criminal No. 8:11-cr-00530-DKC8 (D. Md.). In that case, Liang pleaded guilty to charges of securities fraud and making false statements.”

SEC FILES INJUCTION AGAINST ILLINOIS MAN AND HIS COMPANY

The following excerpt is from the SEC website: November 22, 2011 “The Securities and Exchange Commission today announced that on November 18, it filed a civil injunctive action against Patrick G. Rooney (“Rooney”), a resident of Oakbrook, Illinois, and his company, Solaris Management, LLC (“Solaris Management”), the investment adviser to the Solaris Opportunity Fund, LP (“Solaris Fund”) for the fraudulent misuse of the Solaris Fund’s assets and other illegal conduct. According to the SEC’s complaint, the Solaris Fund is purportedly a non-directional hedge fund with approximately 30 investors and reported assets of $16,277,780 as of December 2008. Contrary to the Solaris Fund’s offering documents and marketing materials, Rooney and Solaris Management allegedly made a radical change in the Solaris Fund’s investment strategy by becoming wholly invested in Positron Corp. (“Positron”), a financially troubled microcap company of which Rooney has been Chairman since 2004. Rooney, who has received compensation from Positron since September 2005, allegedly misused the Solaris Fund’s money by investing over $3.6 million in Positron through both private transactions and market purchases. Many of the private transactions were undocumented while other investments were loans to Positron at 0% interest. The complaint alleges that Rooney and Solaris Management hid the Positron investments and Rooney’s relationship with the company from the Solaris Fund’s investors for over four years. Although Rooney finally told investors about the Positron investments in a March 2009 newsletter, he allegedly lied by telling them he became Chairman to safeguard the Solaris Funds’ investment. The complaint further alleges that these investments benefited Positron and Rooney while providing the Solaris Fund with a concentrated, undiversified, and illiquid position in a cash-poor company with a lengthy track record of losses. The SEC’s complaint, filed in the United States District Court for the Northern District of Illinois, charges Rooney and Solaris Management with violating Section 17(a) of the Securities Act of 1933, Sections 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (“Exchange Act”) and Rules 10b-5 and thereunder, and Sections 206(1), 206(2), and 206(4) of the Investment Advisers Act of 1940 (“Advisers Act”) and Rule 206(4)-8(a)(1) and (a)(2) thereunder. The complaint also charges Rooney with aiding and abetting Solaris Management’s violations of Section 206(4) of the Advisers Act and Rule 206(4)-8(a)(1) thereunder, and Rooney and Solaris Management with aiding and abetting the Solaris Fund’s violation of Section 10(b) of the Exchange Act and Rule 10b-5(b) thereunder, and Section 13(d)(1) of the Exchange Act and Rule 13d-1 thereunder. The SEC is seeking permanent injunctions, disgorgement of any ill-gotten gains plus prejudgment interest and civil monetary penalties against Rooney and Solaris Management, and an officer and director bar against Rooney.”

Thursday, December 1, 2011

SEC GOES AFTER HEDGE FUNDS AND MANGERS FOR ALLEGED FRAUD AND OTHER ALLEGED CRIMES

The following excerpt is from the SEC website: “Washington, D.C., Dec. 1, 2011 — As part of an initiative to combat hedge fund fraud by identifying abnormal investment performance, the Securities and Exchange Commission today announced enforcement actions against three separate advisory firms and six individuals for various misconduct including improper use of fund assets, fraudulent valuations, and misrepresenting fund returns. Under the initiative — the Aberrational Performance Inquiry — the SEC Enforcement Division’s Asset Management Unit uses proprietary risk analytics to evaluate hedge fund returns. Performance that appears inconsistent with a fund’s investment strategy or other benchmarks forms a basis for further scrutiny. In particular, the SEC alleges that the firms and managers engaged in a wide variety of illegal practices in the management of hedge funds or private pooled investment vehicles, including fraudulent valuation of portfolio holdings, misuse of fund assets, and misrepresentations to investors about critical attributes such as performance, assets, liquidity, investment strategy, valuation procedures, and conflicts of interest. “We’re using risk analytics and unconventional methods to help achieve the holy grail of securities law enforcement — earlier detection and prevention,” said Robert Khuzami, Director of the SEC’s Division of Enforcement. “This approach, especially in the absence of a tip or complaint, minimizes both the number of victims and the amount of loss while increasing the chance of recovering funds and charging the perpetrators.” Robert Kaplan and Bruce Karpati, Co-Chiefs of the SEC Enforcement Division’s Asset Management Unit, added, “The extraordinary returns reported by these advisers and portfolio managers were, in most cases, too good to be true. In other cases, outlier returns were a telltale sign that something else was amiss. We are applying analytics across the investment adviser space — beyond performance and beyond hedge funds.” The SEC has filed several enforcement actions to date stemming from this initiative. Of the four actions announced today, three were filed in federal court and one was brought as an administrative proceeding. Michael Balboa and Gilles De Charsonville The SEC today charged two individuals for engaging in a fraudulent scheme to overvalue the reported returns and net asset value of the Millennium Global Emerging Credit Fund. At its peak in October 2008, the hedge fund’s reported assets were $844 million. The SEC’s complaint alleges that Michael Balboa, the fund’s former portfolio manager, schemed with two European-based brokers including Gilles De Charsonville of BCP Securities LLC to inflate the fund’s reported monthly returns and net asset value by manipulating its supposedly independent valuation process. Separately, the U.S. Attorney’s Office for the Southern District of New York announced the arrest of Balboa and simultaneous filing of a criminal action against him. According to the SEC complaint, from at least January to October 2008, Balboa surreptitiously provided De Charsonville and another broker with fictional prices for two of the fund’s illiquid securities holdings for them to pass on to the fund’s outside valuation agent and its auditor. The scheme caused the fund to drastically overvalue these securities holdings by as much as $163 million in August 2008, which in turn allowed the fund to report inflated and falsely-positive monthly returns. By overstating the fund’s returns and overall net asset value, Balboa was able to attract at least $410 million in new investments, deter about $230 million in eligible redemptions, and generate millions of dollars in inflated management and performance fees. The SEC’s investigation, which continues, was conducted by Bill Conway, Brian Fitzpatrick, and Alison Conn of the New York Regional Office. Nancy Brown is leading the SEC’s litigation effort. The SEC acknowledges the assistance and cooperation of the U.S. Attorney, U.S. Postal Inspection Service, U.K. Financial Services Authority, Bermuda Monetary Authority, ComisiĆ³n Nacional del Mercado de Valores, Guernsey Financial Services Authority, and Nigeria Securities and Exchange Commission. ThinkStrategy Capital Management and Chetan Kapur The SEC charged New York-based hedge fund firm ThinkStrategy Capital Management LLC and its sole managing director Chetan Kapur with fraud in connection with two separate hedge funds they managed (ThinkStrategy Capital Fund and TS Multi-Strategy Fund). At its peak in 2008, ThinkStrategy managed approximately $520 million in assets. The SEC’s complaint filed on Nov. 9, 2011 alleges that ThinkStrategy and Kapur engaged in a pattern of deceptive conduct designed to bolster their track record, size, and credentials. In particular, they materially overstated the performance of the Capital Fund and gave investors the false impression that the fund’s returns were consistently positive and minimally volatile. ThinkStrategy and Kapur also repeatedly inflated the firm’s assets, exaggerated the firm’s longevity and performance history, and misrepresented the size and credentials of firm’s management team. ThinkStrategy and Kapur consented to the entry of judgments permanently enjoining them from violating the antifraud provisions of the securities laws, and have agreed to pay financial penalties and disgorgement in an amount to be determined by a federal court. Kapur consented to the entry of an SEC order, instituted Nov. 30, 2011, barring him from association with any investment adviser, broker, dealer, municipal securities dealer, municipal advisor, transfer agent, or nationally recognized statistical rating organization. The SEC’s investigation was conducted by Darren Long, Jeffrey Anderson, and Scott Weisman. Michael Semler is leading the remaining litigation effort. Patrick Rooney and Solaris Management The SEC charged Oakbrook, Ill. resident Patrick G. Rooney and his company Solaris Management LLC for fraudulently misusing the assets of the Solaris Opportunity Fund LP, to which it was the investment adviser. According to the SEC’s complaint filed on Nov. 16, 2011 in federal court in Chicago, Rooney and Solaris made a radical change in the fund’s investment strategy, contrary to the fund’s offering documents and marketing materials, by becoming wholly invested in Positron Corp., a financially troubled microcap company. The SEC alleges that Rooney, who has been Chairman of Positron since 2004 and received salary and stock options from Positron since September 2005, misused the Solaris Fund’s money by investing more than $3.6 million in Positron through both private transactions and market purchases. Many of the private transactions were undocumented while other investments were interest-free loans to Positron. Rooney and Solaris hid the Positron investments and Rooney’s relationship with the company from the fund’s investors for over four years. Although Rooney finally told investors about the Positron investments in a March 2009 newsletter, he allegedly lied by telling them he became Chairman to safeguard the fund’s investments. These investments benefited Positron and Rooney while providing the fund with a concentrated, undiversified, and illiquid position in a cash-poor company with a lengthy track record of losses. The SEC’s investigation was conducted by Andrew Shoenthal, Malinda Grish, Ann Tushaus, Linda Gerstman, and Paul Montoya of the Chicago Regional Office. Timothy Leiman is leading the litigation effort. LeadDog Capital Markets, Chris Messalas and Joseph LaRocco The SEC instituted administrative proceedings against unregistered investment adviser LeadDog Capital Markets LLC and its general partners and owners Chris Messalas and Joseph LaRocco for misrepresenting or failing to disclose material information to investors in the LeadDog Capital LP fund. In proceedings instituted on Nov. 15, 2011, the SEC Division of Enforcement alleges that LeadDog, Messalas, and LaRocco induced investors to invest in a hedge fund they controlled through material misrepresentations and omissions concerning among other things Messalas’s negative regulatory history as a securities professional, compensation received by Messalas and LaRocco in connection with the fund’s investments, and Messalas’s substantial ownership interest in, and control of, some of the same companies to which he directed fund investments. In addition, LeadDog, Messalas, and LaRocco allegedly misrepresented to, and concealed from, existing and prospective investors the substantial conflicts of interests and related party transactions that characterized the fund’s illiquid investments. For example, to induce one elderly investor to invest $500,000 in the fund, LeadDog, Messalas, and LaRocco represented falsely that at least half of the fund’s assets were liquid and could be marked to market each day, and that the investor could exit the fund at any time.”